Asian American
Policy Review

New Means
for Political Empowerment in the Asian Pacific American
Community Spring
2001
Steven
Hill-Center for Voting and Democracy [email protected]
(415) 665-5044
Robert
Richie-Center for Voting and Democracy [email protected] (301)
270-4616

Abstract
In recent years, alternative voting systems have
advanced from being "controversial" to credible options for
political empowerment of racial minority communities. On their own
merits, and as a strategic response to recent U.S. Supreme Court
rulings on voting rights and redistricting, proportional and
semi-proportional voting methods like choice voting, cumulative
voting and limited voting are increasingly used and recognized as a
means to increase minority representation in local, state and even
federal elections. The logic of proportional and semi-proportional
voting systems for minority representation is simply too
comp
elling
to be ignored. Indeed, alternative voting systems may have special
utility for the Asian Pacific American community, which often finds
itself dispersed over a geographic area and not concentrated enough
to benefit from the drawing of majority-minority districts. In fact,
in Los Angeles, New York City and San Francisco, three major cities
with the highest populations of Asian Pacific Americans, the
traditional voting rights strategy of drawing majority-minority
districts has utterly failed APAs, as APAs currently hold only one
out of a total of 77 city council seats elected by single-seat
districts in these three cities. But evidence from New York City,
Los Angeles and San Francisco show that representation for Asian
Pacific Americans would have a much higher chance of success using
proportional and semi-proportional voting systems. This article will
examine the electoral prospects for APAs using these alternative
voting systems, and explore strategies to seek their adoption.

New Means for Political
Empowerment in the Asian Pacific American Community
By Steven Hill and Robert
Richie
In the three
years since Bill Lann Lee became acting head of the Civil Rights
division of the Department of Justice, proportional and
semi-proportional voting systems have advanced from being
"controversial" to credible alternatives for political empowerment.
On their own merits, and as a strategic response to Supreme Court
rulings on voting rights and redistricting, alternative voting
methods like choice voting, limited voting and cumulative voting are
increasingly used and recognized as a means to increase minority
representation in local, state and even federal
elections.1
Under Mr. Lee,
the Voting Section of the Civil Rights division pre-cleared use of
proportional voting systems in numerous jurisdictions. Most
recently, the Justice Department pre-cleared the use of cumulative
voting for school board elections in Amarillo, Texas, a city of more
than 150,000 people (more than 50 jurisdictions in Texas now use
cumulative voting, with the number steadily growing).2 In
1999, the Department of Justice (DOJ) wrote an amicus brief backing
a federal judge's order of cumulative voting for elections to the
city council and park board in Chicago Heights, IL. In September
1999, a representative of the DOJ�s Civil Rights division testified
in favor of a bill in Congress that would allow states to use
proportional and semi-proportional systems to elect their
congressional representatives. After hearing persuasive evidence
from the Asian American Legal Defense and Education Fund (AALDEF), the DOJ denied
pre-clearance to New York City after the state legislature sought to
replace choice voting, a fully proportional voting system, with a
less proportional system for electing the city's local school
boards.3 In its denial, the DOJ noted that the school
boards had a significantly higher percentage of all racial
minorities than any other legislative body in the city and were the
only level of election where Asian Pacific Americans have had
electoral success in New York. All in all, this has been a
remarkable turnaround for alternative voting systems, which came
under attack during the nomination proceedings of Lani Guinier for
the position that Bill Lann Lee eventually
assumed.4
The logic of
proportional and semi-proportional voting systems for minority
representation is too compelling to be held down for long,
particularly in the wake of recent court rulings striking down
majority-minority districts5 -- the so-called Shaw rulings.6
Indeed, alternative voting systems may have special utility for the
Asian Pacific American community which often finds itself dispersed
over a geographic area and therefore not concentrated enough to
benefit from the drawing of majority-minority districts.7
In fact, in Los Angeles, New York City and San Francisco, three
major cities with the highest populations of Asian Pacific
Americans, the traditional voting rights strategy of drawing
majority-minority districts has utterly failed APAs, as APAs
currently hold only one out of a total of 77 city council seats
elected by single-seat districts in these three cities. Thus, this
article will examine the electoral prospects for APAs using a
different strategy than single-seat districts -- namely, multi-seat
districts elected by proportional and semi-proportional voting
systems.
APA Electoral Success in New York City
School Board Elections
The principle behind
a "proportional" system is simple: that any grouping of like-minded
voters should win legislative seats in proportion to its share of
the popular vote (see appendix 1 explaining more detail about
various proportional and semi-proportional systems). Whereas our
current winner-take-all principle awards 100% of the representation
to a 50.1% majority, a proportional system allows voters in a
minority to win a fair share of representation.8 For
example, five one-seat districts could be combined into a single
five-seat district. If APA voters comprise 20% of the vote in this
five seat district, they can elect at least one of the five seats --
even if voting was polarized entirely along racial lines -- rather
than be shut out as they would be in a traditional at-large
election, or in a district-based system where APAs are
geographically dispersed.9
New York City
provides a good example for comparing the differing impact that
proportional representation voting systems and geographic-based
district elections can have on Asian Pacific American electoral
success. When it came time in 1991 to draw the electoral district
map for New York's newly expanded city council, it was possible to
create council districts that represented the interests of African
Americans, Caribbean-born blacks, Puerto Ricans, Dominicans and all
sorts of white subgroups, ranging from ethnic whites to Hasidim, the
gay community of Greenwich Village, conservative Republicans on
Staten Island and limousine liberals on the Upper West Side. With
Asian Pacific Americans making up seven percent of New York's
population, three seats drawn for APAs on New York City's 51-seat
city council might have seemed plausible, or at least one seat
corresponding with the 2.3% Asian Pacific American share of
registered voters in 1993. But there was no single geographic
concentration of Asian Pacific American voters in New York City
large enough to form a majority APA district. Many Asian Pacific
Americans live in APA communities -- in Chinatown or in parts of
Queens -- but those neighborhoods were not linked to one another in
a way that could create compact electoral
districts.10
The only
elections in New York City where Asian Pacific Americans achieve
electoral success are the 32 local school boards. Those positions
are elected by a multi-seat proportional voting system called choice
voting.11 After the DOJ denied a change to a plan that
would have more than tripled the percentage of voter support
necessary to win a seat, the proportional system of choice voting
was retained for the May 1999 elections. Of 21 Asian Pacific
American Pacific American candidates who ran, 15 were successful,
winning seats in 9 of the 32 boards and winning 5% of school board
seats overall.12
The rapidly
increasing participation and success of Asian Pacific American
candidates in the New York Community School Board elections provides
an excellent example of how proportional systems -- and choice
voting in particular -- serve to bring new voices and fresh faces
into New York's elections and legislative bodies. Asian Pacific
Americans have had near-continuous representation on the boards
since 1975, even as no Asian Pacific Americans have won any other
electoral office in the state or city. But after 1986, participation
and electoral success took a dramatic upward swing. The number of
Asian Pacific American winners doubled to four in 1989, then rose to
seven in 1993 (out of 11 APA candidates), to 11 winners (out of 15)
in 1996 and to 15 (out of 21) in 1999 (see chart in appendix
2).13
Choice voting
made these successes possible even though Asian Pacific Americans
comprise less than 20% of the adult population in every school
district. That's because with nine seats on each school board, using
a proportional system like choice voting means that it only requires
about 10% of the vote to win one seat, 20% to win two and so
on.14 Also, choice voting uses what is known as a
"transferable ballot," whereby voters rank candidates, 1,2,3, etc.
If a voter's first choice doesn't win, their vote transfers to their
second choice. These transferable ballots are extremely valuable,
since they promote coalition building, prevent voters from
"splitting" their vote among similar candidates (like competing
APAs) or "wasting" their vote on losing candidates, and allow voters
to choose the candidates they really like, instead of the �lesser of
two evils." These qualities promote participation and engagement --
spurring APAs to run even where they comprised less than 10% of the
population, and to run enough candidates to win three of nine seats
in two districts. Choice voting has provided a similar "gateway" for
other newly organized communities in the City, including, in recent
years, immigrant communities from Russia and the Dominican
Republic.
Use of choice voting for New York's city
council elections, instead of the current 51 single-member districts
system, almost certainly would lead to Asian Pacific American
victories and an increased number of APA candidates. Voter
registration data suggests that Asian Pacific Americans would win at
least two seats in the 2001 city council elections if choice voting
were used in each of the city's five boroughs. Even where Asian
Pacific American candidates were not successful, their decision to
run -- which would likely happen in every borough in the city if
choice voting were adopted -- would help the Asian Pacific American
community define and articulate its interests, raise visibility, and
find allies in the non-Asian Pacific American community.
Proportional Systems In
Practice
Here are a few examples of other
localities where proportional and semi-proportional voting systems
are making a difference.
-
In the
Spring of 2000, the Amarillo Independent School District in Texas,
representing a population of nearly 200,000 people, adopted
cumulative voting. While cumulative voting does not have all the
desirable qualities of choice voting (like ranked ballots), it does
lower the threshold of support necessary to win as much as choice
voting. Blacks and Latinos in Amarillo together make up a quarter of
the city's population, but no black or Latino candidate had won a
seat on the school board in decades. Instituted to settle a voting
rights lawsuit involving MALDEF,
LULAC and the NAACP ,
cumulative voting had an immediate impact. Both a black candidate
and Latino candidate won seats with strong support in their
respective communities; voter turnout increased more than three
times over the most recent school board election; and all parties
in the voting rights settlement expressed satisfaction with the
new system. More than 50 Texas jurisdictions now have adopted
cumulative voting in the 1990s alone. In 1995, Texas governor
George W. Bush signed legislation that allows school districts to
adopt cumulative voting and limited voting.
-
Cumulative
voting and limited voting also have been used in nearly two dozen
localities in Alabama for a decade, as well as localities in
Alamogordo, New Mexico and Sisseton, South Dakota.15
Studies by various political scientists of the elections in Alabama
demonstrate that they have boosted turnout and increased black
representation as much or more as would have occurred if single-seat
districts had instead been used.16 Another study by
political scientist Jerome Gray found that more women were elected
as well.17
-
Black candidate
Bobby Agee, in 1988, was the highest vote-getter in the first
elections using cumulative voting for a seven-seat commission in
Chilton County, AL even though blacks comprised barely 10% of the
population and even though he was outspent by more than 20-1 by the
highest-spending candidate. Most of his supporters, overwhelmingly
black, took advantage of their opportunity to cast (or "cumulate")
all seven of their votes for him rather than spread their votes
among other candidates. The first black commissioner in Chilton
County's history, Agee has twice been re-elected and has been
selected by his white colleagues to be chair of the
commission.18
-
Peoria, IL the
quintessential city of "middle America," uses cumulative voting for
its city council elections. Blacks make up only 20% of the city's
population, but black candidates have won in all three elections for
the five seats in which cumulative voting has been used since a
voting voting rights settlement in 1988. In 1998, a federal judge
imposed cumulative voting in another Illinois voting rights case.
Judge David Coar, who presided over the Illinois congressional
redistricting case in which majority-minority districts in Chicago
were upheld, ordered that Chicago Heights, IL adopt cumulative
voting to elect its city council and park board.19 The
order has been appealed, but the fact that cumulative voting is
allowed by state law and had a very respectable history in the state
increases the chances of the order being upheld.20

A
Case Study: Los Angeles City Council
Elections
The city of Los
Angeles is a textbook example of a situation where geographic
dispersal of the Asian Pacific American vote prevents APAs from
achieving the type of electoral success they have enjoyed in the New
York City community school board elections, or have been achieved by
minorities in Amarillo, Peoria, Alabama, Texas and elsewhere. Los
Angeles also illustrates nicely how a proportional system in
multi-seat districts would allow the Asian Pacific American vote to
become electorally competitive.
The city of Los
Angeles has 15 city council districts, each electing one councilor
representing over 232,000 people -- nearly half the size of a
congressional district. Asian Pacific Americans comprise about 10
percent of the voting age population of Los Angeles, and no more
than 19 percent of the voting age population (1990 census data) in
any one city council district. In most districts, APAs comprise far
less than 19 percent. Not surprisingly, Los Angeles City Council has
no elected Asian Pacific Americans, despite a significant increase
in the APA population since the 1990 census. Latinos comprise 35% of
the voting age population according to 1990 census data, and Latinos
hold three seats on the city council. African-Americans are 13
percent of the city's voting age population (1990 census data), but
are highly concentrated geographically and also have three (20%)
city council seats. Whites are, not surprisingly, over-represented,
holding 9 seats (60%) with only 42% of the voting age
population.21
The current 15
single-seat districts plan for Los Angeles' city council clearly is
a barrier to political representation for Asian Pacific Americans.
But, as the examples below illustrate, the electoral possibilities
for APA voters are far less bleak when using multi-seat districts
and a proportional voting system. In fact, in two scenarios, APAs
actually reach a threshold of electoral viability and
competitiveness.
Three seat
districts in Los Angeles For instance, if we combine three
single-seat city council districts into one three-seat district
using a proportional representation system like choice voting, any
cohesive voting constituency greater than 25 percent can elect a
candidate.2 Smaller constituencies can elect a candidate
by forming coalitions with other similar constituencies.
Accordingly, if we combine some conglomeration of three contiguous
city council districts with the highest APA populations, we find
that the Asian Pacific American vote creeps closer toward the
victory threshold of 25 percent. For instance, combining city
council districts #1, #13 and #14, we arrive at the following ethnic
composition:
Asian Pacific Americans |
15 percent
|
Latinos |
64 percent
|
African-Americans |
3 percent
|
White |
17
percent |
Note that,
comparted to single-seat districts, in this three-seat district the
Asian Pacific American vote is on a relative par with the white vote
in terms of reaching the victory threshold of 25%. With lower voter
turnout in the Asian Pacific American community, it still would be a
challenge for APAs to elect a seat, but it is more possible than
under a single-member district plan. And APAs would form a powerful
"influence vote" for successful candidates to
court.
Using other
combinations of three-seat districts � for instance, combining
districts #1, 4 and 13, or districts #4, 10 and 13 or districts #
10, 13 and 14 � would lead to similar results. Latinos and whites
generally have the best shot at winning the three seats, with
sometimes the third seat being very competitive for Asian Pacific
Americans, as well as for Latinos and African Americans. Whichever
constituency could mobilize their voters and build successful
electoral coalitions would win the seat. In other words, while APAs
numbers would still fall short of the victory threshold of 25%, they
would have a fighting chance to win in this three seat district and
would certainly be influential -- particularly compared to the
current 15 single seat district scheme.
Five seat
districts in Los Angeles Even more interesting possibilities arise
for APA voters in Los Angeles if the 15 city council districts are
combined into three five-seat districts. Under such a scheme, the
APA community's chances of winning a seat on the Los Angeles City
Council improve dramatically. A five-seat district would have a
victory threshold of just under 17 percent of the vote.23
Combining city council districts #1, #4, #10, #13 and #14, the
overall ethnic composition becomes:
Asian Pacific Americans |
15 percent
|
Latinos |
51 percent
|
African-Americans |
10 percent
|
White |
23
percent |
In this
scenario, the Asian Pacific American vote has almost reached the
victory threshold. Needing some 17 percent of the vote to win a seat
means that Latino voters should win two or three seats, and the
white voters should win one or two seats. That leaves one seat still
to be filled, and the Asian Pacific American vote is in its best
position yet to fill that seat. This would be a very competitive
district for APAs, facilitating mobilization of APA candidates,
voters and resources.
These
simulations are calculated using voting age population based on 1990
census data. Most experts agree that the Asian Pacific American
population has increased significantly relative to other populations
in Los Angeles, especially compared to whites and African-Americans.
Thus, it is likely that the immediate chances of Asian Pacific
American electoral success will be even better in a multi-seat
proportional voting scheme than estimated here. Also, these
simulations assume that APAs vote in blocs or tend to support one
particular candidate. While such a generalization is never
absolutely true, and perhaps less true for APA's than for Latinos
and African-American, racially polarized voting is certainly an
on-the-ground reality that has contributed to the ability of APAs to
compete electorally in New York City school board elections. Still,
intra-ethnic competition must be factored into any estimates of
electoral viability.

Case
Study Number Two: San Francisco Elections for County Board of
Supervisors
For the 2000
county elections, San Francisco switched to an 11 single-seat
district system from an at-large plurality system electing 11 seats
to the Board of Supervisors. During these elections, APAs suffered a
dramatic decline in representation, from three seats to
one.24 While APAs constitute approximately 30 percent
(1990 Census data) of the city's population, they now have only nine
percent of the representation due to geographic dispersion of the
APA population and the fact that the Chinatown district, drawn as a
majority-minority Asian district (55 percent APA, 1990 Census),
actually elected a white liberal, not an Asian. The lone APA
supervisor, an incumbent, instead was elected
from the Asian-leaning Sunset district (46%
APA).
If we combine
three single-seat districts together in San Francisco into one
three-seat district (as we did in the Los Angeles analysis above)
with a 25 percent victory threshold, we see a much different story.
For instance, combining supervisorial districts 1, 4 and 7 we
discover that APAs comprise about 40 percent of that three-seat
district area and whites about 49 percent. If we combine
supervisorial districts 3, 6, and 10 we find that APAs comprise
about 37 percent of this multi-seat district, with whites at 28
percent, African-Americans at 18 percent and Latinos at 11 percent.
In both of these three-seat districts APAs would elect at least one
seat per district, possibly two, for a total of 2-4 seats. Combining
districts 8, 9 and 11 produces a three-seat district with an APA
population of 21%, another competitive district for APAs possibly to
win one seat, or certainly to be influential. Thus, proportional
representation likely would significantly boost APA electoral
success in San Francisco, just like it would in Los Angeles and New
York City.

Addressing
concerns about proportional and semi-proportional systems
In this section,
we will address a few of the more common questions and concerns
raised about proportional and semi-proportional voting
systems.
Wouldn�t larger
districts make it more expensive and therefore more difficult for
minority candidates to run? Under
proportional and semi-proportional systems, minorities have been
able to win their fair share of representation in numerous
elections, even when outspent. They are able to do this because,
with proportional systems, successful candidates need a smaller
percentage of votes to win. Bobby Agee finished first in his Chilton
County election, even though he was greatly outspent, by asking
supporters to �cumulate� all their votes for him. Recent studies by
our Center for Voting and Democracy and Democracy South found that
in North Carolina and Vermont, both of which use a mix of one-seat
districts and multi-seat districts, candidates actually have spent
less money in the bigger,
multi-seat district elections than in the one-seat
districts.25 There are two reasons for this apparent
paradox: candidates from one party can pool some of their expenses
(activities designed to get out the vote, mailings, some
advertisements, etc.); and it may be harder to pursue negative
campaigning when there are several viable candidates on the ballot.
The head-to-head combat of single-member districts appears to
escalate the need for campaign spending.
Won't
proportional voting systems be too confusing for voters?
Exit polls taken
in Texas and elsewhere have demonstrated that voters understand the
voting rules of alternative systems like cumulative
voting.26 Proportional systems are used in many American
elections and in most other well-established democracies around the
world. Voters in these elections have no trouble using them -- as
evidenced by the higher voter turnout rates seen in most nations
that use proportional systems. Some proportional systems are very
simple to describe; others sound more complicated when first
described, but experience shows that voters quickly grasp and learn
the new rules. Educational campaigns instructing voters how to vote
can also aid with the transition.
Won't these
systems undercut neighborhood representation? No, because with
proportional and semi-proportional systems, you need a smaller
percentage of votes to win, allowing candidates to target their
campaigning to certain parts of the city, if they wish. In
Cambridge, MA, where choice voting is used to elect their city
council, 5 out of 9 winning candidates typically have a core base of
support in specific neighborhoods. Most neighborhoods consistently
elect a representative from their area, as geography often is a
factor in how some people vote. In Japan, local elections use
limited voting for most city elections, and neighborhoods are also
quite well represented, as neighborhood associations are often the
most significant political players at that level of
election.
Does advocacy of
proportional representation undercut voting rights strategies using
single-seat districts? No, because
proportional and semi-proportional systems clearly can co-exist with
single-member districts as voting rights remedies. Some cities like
Peoria combine these approaches (districts with cumulative voting)
in the same election. In states like Texas, North Carolina and
Alabama, where many jurisdictions have adopted limited voting or
cumulative voting, other localities have moved to single-seat
districts. At the very least, proportional systems are a sensible
back-up option when single-seat districts cannot be drawn due to
geographic dispersion of the minority constituency, or due to
judicial or legislative opposition.
Reapportionment
and Redistricting The rising interest in alternative voting systems
obviously is not occurring in a vacuum. Voting Rights Act provisions
on redistricting have divided and preoccupied the Supreme Court more
than any other issue the past ten years. The Court has heard
arguments on cases involving voting rights and redistricting each
term since its Shaw v.
Reno ruling in 1993, often producing bitterly contested 5-4
rulings that have had the general -- if still poorly defined --
impact of limiting to what degree states can use race in drawing
legislative district lines. In a bid to make some lemonades out of
the Supreme Court's lemons, some long-time voting rights experts
have reluctantly outlined the rationalization for accepting Shaw's
"bizarre-shape" test over Miller's "dominant-purpose"
test as the "lesser of two evils."27
The
traditional standard used by the courts to determine voting rights
standing has been to demonstrate the ability to draw a
majority-minority district � a standard that has always plagued
geographically dispersed minorities like APAs. But in a 1998 Harvard Civil Rights-Civil
Liberties Law Review article, Steven Mulroy, a Department of
Justice civil rights attorney, argued for a different
yardstick,28 proposing that Voting Rights Act liability
may be established and alternative remedies obtained even where
plaintiffs cannot draw a compact majority-minority district but can
demonstrate sufficient numbers to reach the victory threshold of
viability -- the aforementioned Droop threshold -- necessary for
alternative voting systems. Using Mulroy's legal approach would
still allow the drawing of majority-minority districts if that
intervention proved to be the most effective. But it would also
allow use of other interventions like proportional representation
when majority-minority districts cannot be drawn due to geographic
dispersion of the targeted constituency or political/judicial
opposition. Thus, Mulroy's approach is more comprehensive and a
powerful tool in voting rights lawsuits, offering to dispersed
minority groups like APAs a "way out" of a dilemma posed by the
race-conscious imperative of the Voting Rights Act and the
race-neutral limits of Shaw
v. Reno.
But there can be
pragmatic arguments for proportional systems quite apart from the
legal battles over Shaw. As civil rights attorneys have
discovered in more than fifty Texas jurisdictions with cumulative
voting and in the more than two dozen counties and cities in North
Carolina and Alabama that have settled with limited voting,
proportional and semi-proportional systems sometimes are a good fit
with local conditions. Perhaps the minority community is more
geographically dispersed than necessary for a single-seat district
plan -- like the Asian Pacific American communities in New York
City, Los Angeles and San Francisco, where majority-minority
districts have utterly failed to adequately represent APAs, electing
only one APA out of a total of 77 local government seats. Perhaps a
small jurisdiction wants to avoid redistricting every decade. In
some multi-racial communities, small and large, a citywide
proportional plan is the easiest way for different racial minorities
to elect representation without the pitfalls of gerrymandering and
perennial lawsuits.
Local government
is an obvious place for considering proportional plans -- the
calculations of what it takes to win representation are quite
straightforward. Redistricting and reapportionment, especially in
racially diverse and polyglot cities like Los Angeles, New York City
and San Francisco pose several vexing questions: should single-seat
districts continue to be the preferred Voting Rights remedy, even
when such districts produce electoral success for certain minority
groups at the expense of other minority groups? Conversely, if it
can be demonstrated that multi-seat proportional voting schemes will
do a better job than single-seat districts at giving political
representation to all racial minority groups in a given
locality, isn�t there a Voting Rights imperative that such schemes
be utilized? Knowing what we now know about the ineffectiveness of
single-seat districts for yielding electoral success to Asian
Pacific American voters in New York City, Los Angeles, San Francisco
and elsewhere, isn't it time for the voting rights community to
explore alternative voting systems that will be fair to
everyone?
Given the new
and vague rules established by the courts for drawing single-seat
districts, alternative voting system show great promise for
providing the most equitable solution for all.
[Steven Hill is
the western regional director of the Center for Voting and
Democracy. Rob Richie is the Center�s executive director. They are
the co-authors of Reflecting All of Us (Beacon Press 1999), and Hill
is author of a forthcoming book from Routledge Press in Fall 2001.
For more information, see www.fairvote.org, email: [email protected], call
301-270-4616 or write to: PO Box 60037, Washington, DC
20039.]

Appendix
1: A Lexicon of Proportional/Semi-proportional Voting
Systems
Proportional
representation is more a principle that any specific voting system,
and the principle is this: that groupings of like-minded voters
should win representation in proportion to their voting strength.
Certain voting systems fulfill this principle more than others, and
various proportional and semi-proportional systems exist. The
details of different systems matter, but the key point is that all
voters are empowered to mobilize and win their fair share of
representation. There are partisan and non-partisan forms; more than
200 localities in the United States use one of three non-partisan
systems: cumulative voting, limited voting or choice
voting.1 Candidates are elected at-large or in multi-seat
districts (constituencies electing more than one representative).
Limited voting, cumulative voting and choice voting are based on
voting for candidates (not parties) and already are used in local
elections in the United States.
Limited
Voting: a
semi-proportional system where voters either cast fewer votes than
the number of seats or political parties nominate fewer candidates
than there are seats. The greater the difference between the number
of seats and the number of votes, the greater the opportunities for
minority representation. Versions of limited voting are used in
Washington, D.C., Philadelphia (PA), Hartford (CT) and numerous
local jurisdictions. It has been used to resolve at least 25 voting
rights cases. Limited voting with one vote � the method fairest to
those in the minority � is used for nearly all municipal elections
in Japan.
Example: In a
race to elect five candidates, voters could be limited to one or two
votes. The highest vote-getters (simple plurality) -- the five
candidates with the most votes � win.
Cumulative
Voting: a
semi-proportional system where voters cast as many votes as there
are seats to be elected, but unlike a traditional at-large system
voters are not limited to giving only one vote to a candidate.
Instead, they can put multiple votes on one or more candidates. In a
five-seat race, a voter can give all five of her votes to one
candidate, or three votes to one candidate and two votes to another
candidate, etc. She can "cumulate" or "spend" her votes however she
wishes.
Cumulative
voting was used to elect the Illinois state legislature from 1870 to
1980. In recent years it has been used to resolve voting rights
cases for city council elections in numerous jurisdictions in Texas,
Illinois, New Mexico, South Dakota and
elsewhere.
Example: In a
race to elect five candidates, voters can cast one vote for five
candidates, five votes for one candidate or a combination in
between. The five highest vote-getters (simple plurality)
win.
Choice
voting: a fully
proportional system also known as "single transferable vote" and
"preference voting." Choice voting is the most common proportional
system found in other English-speaking nations. Each voter has one
vote, but can rank as few or as many candidates as they wish in
order of preference (1, 2, 3, 4, etc.). Ballots are counted like a
series of runoffs, eliminating candidates with least support
Candidates win by reaching a "victory threshold" roughly equal to
the number of votes divided by the number of seats. The ranked
ballots facilitate coalition-building and allows candidates to run
without fear of being a "spoiler" that is splitting the
vote.
Choice voting
is used for city council and school board elections in Cambridge, MA
(since 1941), and their city council has had consistent black
representation since the 1950s. Choice voting also is used for local
school board elections in New York City, where it has consistently
produced high rates of representation for blacks, Latinos and Asian
Pacific Americans (higher than the district elections used for city
council and other offices). Choice voting was used until the 1950s
in Cincinnati, Cleveland, New York City and other American cities,
and resulted in fair racial, ethnic and partisan representation. The
Republic of Ireland and Australia use choice voting for national
legislative elections, and have done so for decades.
1. In
addition, different varieties of proportional systems are used in
most well-established democracies, and of the 36 major democracies
with a high Freedom House human rights rating and a population over
two million people, only two -- the United States and Canada -- use
exclusively winner-take-all elections for national elections. This year
South Africa held its second election using proportional
representation; once again, voter turnout and voter respect for the
outcome were high, and all racial groupings elected a fair share of
seats without gerrymandering a single district. See Andrew Reynolds
and Ben Reilly. The
International IDEA Handbook of Electoral System Design.
Stockholm: Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance, 1997,
page 20.

Authors�
Biographies
Robert
Richie is the
executive director of the Center for Voting and Democracy (www.fairvote.org), a non-profit
organization that researches and educates about the impact of voting
systems and the legislative redistricting process on political
representation, voter turnout, accountable governance and campaign
finance reform. The Center has advised judges, plaintiffs and
defendants in some of the most significant voting rights cases of
our times. Mr. Richie is co-author of Reflecting All of Us (Beacon Press) and his
commentaries have appeared in the New York Times, Washington Post,
Wall Street Journal, Roll Call, Nation, National Civic Review,
Social Policy, Boston Review, Christian Science Monitor, Miami
Herald and dozens of newspapers via the Knight-Ridder wire service.
Richie is an expert on both international and domestic electoral
systems and has directed the Center (whose president is former
Member of Congress John Anderson) since its founding in 1992. Richie
has addressed the Voting Rights Section of the U. S. Department of
Justice, the Texas Commission on Judicial Efficiency, the annual
conventions of the National Association of Counties, American Political Science
Association and the National Conference of State Legislatures,
and testified in special sessions before numerous charter
commissions and state legislative committees. He has been a panelist
at national conferences of organizations like the National Rainbow Coalition,
Joint Center for Political and
Economic Studies, Feminist Majority
Foundation, NAACP LDEF, Voting Integrity
Project, U.S. Term
Limits
and National Black Caucus of
State Legislators. Richie has worked closely with government
officials and community leaders seeking to improve and reform New
York's Community School Board elections. He is a frequent source for
print, radio and television journalists. He can be reached at:
[email protected],
301-270-4616 or Center for Voting and Democracy, PO Box 60037,
Washington, DC 20039.
Steven
Hill is the western
regional director of the Center for Voting and Democracy. He is the
co-author of Reflecting All
of Us, published by Beacon Press. He is a frequent contributor
of political commentaries to the Knight-Ridder wire service, and his
articles and commentaries have appeared in dozens of newspapers and
magazines, including the Washington Post, New York Times, Los
Angeles Times, Wall Street Journal, The Nation, Ms., Roll Call,
Miami Herald, Baltimore Sun, Chicago Tribune, Houston Chronicle, San
Antonio Express-News, Providence Journal, Hartford Courant,
Salon.com, Mother Jones Wire, TomPaine.com, Asian Week, Christian
Science Monitor, San Francisco Chronicle, Boston Review, Social
Policy, In These Times, and many others. His work has also been
published in the academic press, including Representation: Journal of
Representative Democracy (Winter 1998), Inroads, a Journal of
Opinion (Issue 7, 1998), and the anthologies Making Every Vote Count
(Broadview Press) and Civil
Rights Since 1787 (New York University Press). He co-authored a
paper presented at the Western Political Science Association
convention in 1997. He is a frequent guest on radio and TV shows,
and has given presentations, testimony and workshops to numerous
conferences, charter commissions, legislative committees and
organizations. He is a researcher of European politics and political
institutions, having conducted research trips in the past two years
to Brussels, Paris, Rome, Amsterdam and Bonn. He can be reached at:
[email protected], (415) 665-5044, Center for Voting and Democracy,
P.O. Box 22411, San Francisco, CA 94122.

Endnotes
8. See Rich DeLeon,
Lisel Blash and Steven Hill, 1997. �The Politics of Electoral Reform
in San Francisco: Preference Voting Versus Districts Versus
Plurality At-Large.� (Paper presented at the 1997 Annual Meeting of
the Western Political Science Association, Tucson, AZ, 13-15 March
1997).
13. Letters to Department of Justice by
Asian American Legal Defense and Education Fund, September 1998 �
February 1999.
18. Richard H. Pildes
and Kristen A. Donoghue. 1995. "Cumulative Voting in the United
States." University of
Chicago Legal Forum (1995): 241-313.
|