TomPaine.com Features Commentaries on Reform by CVD's Rob Richie and John AndersonJanuary 24, 2001 The news web site TomPaine.com featured articles by The Center for Voting and Democracy's leaders and other voting system experts in its "op-ad" that ran simultaneously in the New York Times and on its web site. CVD executive director Rob Richie writes about reform of the Electoral College, CVD president John Anderson makes the case for instant runoff voting, Behind the Ballot Box author Douglas Amy writes about proportional representation and Australian scholar Ben Reilly provides an international perspective on instant runoff voting. See the commentaries by Richie and Anderson below. For the full set of articles, go to www.TomPaine.com. Meddling
with Reform
If
you thought Election 2000 was distorted by partisanship, keep your
eyes on the push for electoral reform.
Summary: The
nation�s outrage with the electoral system is catalyzing long-needed
reform, but will partisans exploit this opportunity for their own
advantage? Let�s call it
�Floridamok� the protracted partisan battle that yielded Electoral
College victory for George W. Bush despite Al Gore�s half-million
ballot lead in the national popular vote. The resulting furor has
spurred a national reexamination of the quirky Electoral College
system by which we elect our presidents. But reformers, beware!
Partisans from both major camps can see opportunity in the outrage
inspired by Bush vs. Gore: the chance to hijack the reform impulse
and manipulate it to their own advantage. Take Grover Norquist,
for example. He�s the renowned conservative strategist whose group,
Americans for Tax Reform, is to some observers synonymous with
�Grand Old Party.� In December Norquist revealed to the National
Review how partisans could tweak electoral reform toward his
favorite team. He suggested that Republican-controlled states like
Michigan, New Jersey and Pennsylvania � all of which gave their
electors to Al Gore in 2000 and to Bill Clinton in 1992 and 1996 �
switch to allocating electoral votes by congressional district,
thereby assuring that Republicans would win at least some electoral
votes in those states in 2004. Norquist�s suggestion
reminds us that individual states are vested by the Constitution
with the sole power to decide how electoral votes are allocated.
Electoral reform will be hammered out in the state houses, subject
as they are to control by one party or the other - and to partisan
shenannigans. The question is whether
statehouse leaders will take advantage of the current reform climate
to seek to benefit one party over others or to benefit all voters
and the nation as a whole. The Fixes
There are several
potential fixes to the presidential election
system. The most obvious one is
scrapping the Electoral College in favor of direct election by
popular vote, just as we elect nearly every other office in the
nation. Direct election is a pre- condition to full political
equality in presidential elections. Only direct election can ensure
that all votes count equally no matter where people live. Only
direct election can provide clear incentives for campaigns to give
at least some degree of attention to every voter instead of only
those in selected states. Despite these
advantages and consistent majority support in the polls, however,
direct election is for the moment unlikely. Such a significant
Constitutional change would take strong bi- partisan support --
currently not in evidence -- to address some small-population
states' mistaken worry that they would be ignored in national
elections under a direct vote.
But states right now can take three significant steps to mend
the Electoral College without ending it: instant runoff voting (IRV)
and allocation of electoral votes by proportional representation
(PR) or by congressional district, as Norquist suggests. There are
important differences, including the degree to which each reform
creates partisan advantage. Of the three proposals,
instant runoff voting is least subject to partisanship and would do
the most for a state's voters It would maintain winner-take-all
allocation of electors, but at least ensure that the winner has a
clear majority by simulating a traditional runoff election.
Here�s how IRV works:
Rather than just vote for a single candidates, voters have the
option to rank the candidates in order of preference: first choice,
second choice, third choice. If a candidate receives a majority of
first choices, he or she wins. But if not, the candidate with the
fewest votes is eliminated -- thus failing to advance to the runoff
-- and a second round of counting occurs. Ballots cast for the
eliminated candidate now count for the voters� second choice on each
ballot, just as if those voters had come back to the polls for a
runoff election. Rounds of counting continue until candidate wins a
majority of valid ballots -- which always will happen by the time
the field is reduced to two, just as in a traditional runoff
election. Instant runoff voting
would eliminate all talk of "spoiler" candidacies. It would create
the situation where, as independent presidential candidate John
Anderson has put it, a voter can vote for his favorite candidate
without fear of electing his least- favorite candidate.
Well-tested from
decades of use in Australia and Ireland, IRV would only require
states to purchase modern voting equipment that can allow voters to
rank-order the candidates -- purchases many states expect to do
anyway in the wake of the controversy in Florida. It already is
under serious consideration for presidential elections in such
states as Vermont (where the proposal is supported by the League of
Women Voters, Grange and Common Cause, among others), Alaska (where
it will be on the statewide ballot in 2002) and New
Mexico. �Proportional
representation� allocates electoral votes in proportion to the
statewide popular vote rather than by the current "winner-take-all"
method. Supported as a national change by both Franklin Roosevelt
and Richard Nixon during their presidencies and already used in most
presidential primaries and in legislative races in most
well-established democracies around the world, proportional
allocation would ensure that more voters can help the candidate of
their choice win electoral votes. If a candidate were to win 40% of
the popular vote in the state, that candidate would win 40% of the
state's electoral votes -- a truer reflection of voter intentions
than the funhouse mirror generated by winner-take-all. A minimum
threshold of support necessary for candidates to win electoral votes
could be set to allay concerns about splinter candidates gaining
electors despite having no chance to win. The congressional
district plan breaks up statewide winner- take-all majorities
differently. Already used by Maine and Nebraska, it assigns
electoral votes according to the results in each congressional
district in a state, with the two Senate electors going to the
overall statewide winner (states get one electoral vote for each
senator and representative). Although one candidate has won all
electoral votes in each election in Maine and Nebraska since they
adopted the system, bigger states typically will have a mix of
districts that lean strongly toward one party or another. Candidates
without a chance to win the statewide vote might still be able to
win certain districts. Third-party candidates would be unlikely to
win electoral votes -- Ross Perot did not come close to winning any
congressional district despite winning nearly a fifth of the popular
vote in 1992. Enter Grover
The problem with the
last two reforms is that, unlike IRV, they have very different
partisan impacts based on whether states enact them alone or in
coordination with other states. Whatever genuine civic support there
might be for them, state leaders are unlikely to pursue them on mere
philosophical merits lest they put their state at a disadvantage in
national elections. That�s because any reform likely to guarantee a
more-equal division of electoral votes in one state could lead
presidential candidates to divert their resources to competitive
winner-take-all states where campaign energy could swing a state's
entire bloc of electoral votes. This phenomenon is common in
Republican presidential primaries, which now use a mix of approaches
but are generally moving toward statewide winner-take-all allocation
in order to compete with other winner-take-all
states. More importantly,
reforms that allocate electors proportionally or according to
congressional districts are vulnerable to political manipulation at
the state level. Although there are well-intentioned reformers who
support these changes, they also draw the attention of deeply
partisan strategists - enter Grover Norquist. Suppose one party
controls both the legislature and governor's mansion in a
winner-take-all state. But suppose also that this party's
presidential candidate has a good chance of losing the state. State
leaders suddenly can become interested in "fair" allocation of
electoral votes because half a loaf - some proportion of the state's
electors - is better than none at all. Given the partisan
nature of how congressional districts are created in redistricting,
allocation by congressional district is particularly problematic.
Most districts strongly favor one party or the other, often due to
political gerrymandering to protect congressional incumbents --
incumbents' 99% re-election rate in 1998 and 2000 is no accident.
Problems with the
congressional district approach are exemplified by Pennsylvania, one
of Norquist's proposed targets. When the presidential vote is
counted statewide, Democrats do well -- over the last three
elections, Democratic candidates won the state�s 23 electoral votes
by comfortable margins. But Democratic voters are relatively
concentrated in a few areas, and when it comes to the state�s U.S.
House districts, there is a decided Republican tilt. In 1996 Bill
Clinton ran behind his statewide vote average in 13 of 21 districts,
and despite Gore�s victory in the state in 2000, George W. Bush
probably won a majority of the districts in 2000 (presidential
results by district will not be available until this spring).
This Republican edge
exists now even before Pennsylvania�s Republicans have a whack at
redistricting later this year. By tweaking a few districts here and
there, they could (and probably will) enhance their control of more
districts. This makes it quite possible that under a congressional
district allocation method of choosing presidential electors, a
Republican candidate could win most of the state's electoral votes
even when losing the statewide popular vote. Michigan Republicans
might have a similar opportunity, given that they control
redistricting and Democratic votes are heavily concentrated in
Detroit. Allocating electoral
votes by congressional district would give a distinct advantage to
Republicans if adopted nationwide, although the approach would not
benefit Republicans in every state -- which is why some states
controlled by Democrats, particularly in the South, may seek to
change statewide winner- take-all rules. . The Democratic vote
typically is concentrated in urban areas -- a concentration that led
Democrats to win 24 of the 26 two-major-party congressional races
won in 2000 with more than 80 percent of the vote. George W. Bush
almost certainly won more House districts than Al Gore in 2000.
Combined with his victory in ten more states (giving him 20 more
electoral votes than Gore under the district system), he would have
won a comfortable electoral college win with the system despite his
losing popular vote. If the method had been used in 1960, Richard
Nixon would have beaten John Kennedy. Besides opening the
door to gerrymandering, the congressional district method has other
problems. Just like the current system, it leaves most voters in a
position where their vote won't matter much in a nationally
competitive election, as most people will live in a state and a
congressional district that tilts strongly to one major party
candidate. Thus, all the campaign resources still will be focused on
a relatively small portion of the electorate - the "swing vote" in
the swing districts and states. In addition, unless combined with
instant runoff voting, congressional district allocation maintains
the problem of candidates winning with less than a majority of the
vote due to "spoiler" minor party candidacies. The simplest, most
powerful change for electing our president would be direct election
combined with instant runoff voting to ensure that the winner
represents as many Americans as possible. Instant runoff voting for
now can be pursued state by state. Proportional allocation of
electoral votes is worth serious consideration if done all at once
across the nation, but that would require Constitutional change.
Allocating electoral votes by congressional district is the most
problematic reform. It shares the downsides of proportional
allocation, but has the significant additional problem of perverting
fair results due to partisan gerrymandering. So, when partisans like
Grover Norquist suddenly take interest in this "fair" method or
electoral reform, watch out. The partisan spirit of Floridamok has
not subsided, and it may distort the reforms demanded by the voting
public. A Clear
Majority Winner in 2000
As the nation grows
accustomed to George W. Bush having captured Florida's electoral
votes and, with them, the presidency, we must not overlook an
important fact. In 2000, a majority of valid, unquestionably legal
votes in Florida -- and indeed in the nation -- were cast for either
Democrat Al Gore or Ralph Nader. Given that most Nader voters
preferred Gore to Republican George W. Bush, there is little doubt
that in a one-on-one race on November 7, Al Gore would have defeated
Bush in Florida. But because of Nader's candidacy and our antiquated
plurality voting system, that majority vote for Gore was fractured.
As a result, Bush is our president. Some argue that Nader
"spoiled" the election for Gore. The spoiler charge that plagued
Nader's campaign this year is a familiar one. In 1992, Ross Perot
undercut the re-election bid of Republican George Bush. In 1980,
when I ran for president as an independent after abandoning the
Republican primaries, I was labeled a spoiler even when polling near
25 percent. My candidacy was said to deprive voters of the clear
choice between Republican Ronald Reagan and Democratic incumbent
Jimmy Carter. Never mind that my platform clearly attracted many
people uncomfortable with this choice, just as Ross Perot, Ralph
Nader and other third party candidates have attracted genuine
support. I sympathize both with
the major party candidates who don't want to have their candidacies
spoiled and the minor party candidates who want to be considered as
more than spoilers. On the one hand, it is understandable that major
party candidates don't want to lose only because some of their
constituency support a third party candidate. We should not be
surprised when they seek to keep third party candidates off the
ballot and exclude them from debates. But such exclusionary
practices must not be the answer to the spoiler dilemma,
particularly given our shrinking voter participation. Having more
candidates run in general elections and take part in debates
strengthens democracy. As indicated by Perot's impact on the 1992
presidential campaign and Jesse Ventura's impact on Minnesota's
gubernatorial election in 1998, third party candidates can increase
turnout and interest in elections. More people watch debates, more
ideas are discussed, and, ultimately, more people
vote. Fortunately, there is a
way to resolve this conflict between the self-interest of major
party candidates and democratic principles. There is no need to
accept electoral rules in which voting for your favorite candidate
can contribute directly to the election of your least favorite.
The root of the problem
is that, unlike in most democracies, here the candidate with the
most votes wins all, even if opposed by a majority of voters. By
allowing candidates to win without a majority of the vote, third
party candidates and independents can be "spoilers" if they split a
major party candidate's vote. One way to resolve the
problem is allow two rounds of voting. In the first round, all
candidates run. If no candidate wins a majority, then the top two
candidates face off in a "runoff." In a two-person race, a candidate
cannot win without obtaining a majority. There is another,
better solution that is practiced in London, Ireland and Australia:
instant runoff voting. Any state could implement instant runoff
voting immediately for its federal elections, including the
presidential race. There are significant efforts underway to enact
instant runoff voting for federal elections in such states as
Alaska, New Mexico and Vermont. Instant runoff voting also would be
the best way to conduct a direct election for
president. Here's how it works. In
instant runoff voting, people are given the freedom to do more than
vote for just one candidate. Instead, they can rank the candidates
in order of preference: 1, 2, 3. If a candidate receives a majority
of first choices, the election is over. But if not, the
ballot-counters simulate a runoff by eliminating the candidate with
the fewest votes In this round, all the ballots cast for a remaining
candidate stay right with that candidate, while the second choice of
voters who cast ballots for the eliminated candidate are now
tallied. If this new count results in a majority winner, the
election is over. If not, the next weakest candidate is eliminated,
and everyone's remaining top choice is counted. The rounds continue
until there is a majority winner -- there always will be a majority
winner once the field is reduced to two, just as in a traditional
runoff election. With instant runoff
voting, we would determine a true majority winner in one election -
avoiding all the extra expense, campaign financing and hassle of a
second round of voting�. And we would forever banish the spoiler
concept. Voters would not have to calculate possible perverse
consequences of voting for their favorite candidate. They could vote
their hopes, not their fears. With instant runoff
voting, liberals who liked Nader but worried about Bush could have
ranked Nader first and Gore second. Similarly, some conservatives
could have ranked Reform Party candidate Pat Buchanan first and Bush
second. Rather than contributing to Gore's or Bush's defeat, Nader
and Buchanan instead could have better stimulated debate and
mobilized new voters that would have helped the major party
candidate closest to them in political views. Our primitive voting
system was this year's real spoiler. Instant runoff voting would
give us a more participatory, vital democracy where candidates could
be judged on their merits and the will of the majority could
prevail. And this year, we would have settled the election at the
ballot box, not in the courts. [John B. Anderson is the president of the Center for Voting and Democracy (www.fairvote.org) in Takoma Park, Maryland. He served in Congress from 1961 to 1981 and was an independent presidential candidate in 1980.] |